
Sign up to save your podcasts
Or
If unemployment is so low, why aren’t workers getting cut in on the deal? That’s a question that our guest, economist Marshall Steinbaum, has been trying to answer. In a new study, which was featured in the New York Times, Steinbaum and his co-authors find that one of the main reasons that wages have not kept pace is that most local labor markets are highly concentrated. Only a few companies are hiring and, as a result, these dominant firms have the power to set wages below the rate that people would earn in a more competitive labor market.
(The technical term for this is “monopsony,” a close cousin of monopoly, which refers to a situation in which a buyer — of labor, in this case — has the power to dictate the price.)
Steinbaum, who’s Research Director at the Roosevelt Institute, joins Building Local Power host and ILSR co-director Stacy Mitchell to discuss his research and how elected officials can fix the broken market for labor.
Photo Courtesy of Roosevelt Institute
Our guest, Marshall Steinbaum, provided a book recommendation, and we’ll also share some of his original research:
Map courtesy of The Roosevelt Institute with this caption: “A map of the average concentration of the 200 occupations that appear most frequently in the Burning Glass data, by Commuting Zone.”
Gies grew up on a farm and he spent a lot of time as a kid tinkering with farm equipment. When he grew up, he decided to become a farm equipment mechanic, repairing tractors and the like, and he really loved the work. He worked for a John Deere dealership, owned by a Wisconsin company called Riesterer & Schnell, which owns 12 different John Deere dealerships across Wisconsin.
But Gies actually left that job because he said they demanded far too many hours of work for too little pay, so three years ago he quit. The problem is that all these years later, despite being surrounded by farms, and despite looking for work, he hasn’t been able to find another job repairing farm equipment. Most of the seven John Deere dealerships within an hour’s drive of his house are actually owned by Riesterer & Schnell, the same company that he left.
They have a monopoly on the supply of jobs repairing farm equipment. It turns out that this is a common situation in most regions of country. Many occupations are dominated by just a few employers at most. As a result, there’s no real competition for labor. Economists have recently began to study this problem and what they’re finding is quite striking. Concentration has played a significant role in holding down wages over the last 20 years. It’s one of the key reasons American workers have not gotten a raise, even as productivity has soared.
Today on the show, our guest is Marshall Steinbaum, one of the economists whose been at the forefront of this research and whose work was featured in that New York Times story. Marshall is Research Director at the Roosevelt Institute. Marshall, welcome to the show.
Even as the economy grows, there’s an equal division of the pie among the owners of labor and capital over time, and consequently, the total absolute amount that’s going to workers would be rising over time as the economy gets larger.
What has been going on now since 2000 at least is that the share of the pie that goes to workers has been in decline, and it’s been in decline in a very specific way. That share of the pie declines when there’s been a recession, as there was in 2000-2001, and then again in the Great Recession, starting in 2008. And then, it’s basically flat during the resulting recovery that follows the recession.
That is the phenomenon that I think is getting increasing attention from labor economists, because it cannot be explained by any of the data, by any of the observables that economists would typically think of as causing long run changes in wages for individuals, and for the economy as a whole. Notably, that would be education, so the view among economists is that what determines how much individual workers get over the course of their lives is what their skills are, and you can tell what their skills are from their level of education and their level of experience in the labor market.
Increasingly, education is just not a very good way of discerning who gets what in the labor market. We had already known this before my paper came out, about monopsony specifically, because there’s an increasing inequality in interfirm earnings among workers. What that means is the company you work for matters more in determining your wages than it previously did. Rather than it be your own qualities, your own data that’s like education and race or gender, that is relevant to knowing what your total income is, it matters more who you work for and their position in the economy, and their position vis-a-vis workers.
I think that had already primed the economics scholarly community to look for explanations for who gets what that are at odds with received wisdom, at least as its existed for the last couple of decades in economics.
But then what’s been really unusual is that in the recovery periods, workers are not seeing their wages go up. And I think most people who are listening will recognize that problem maybe in their own lives. What’s really striking right now is I think, if I read this correctly, unemployment is now at a 17 year low. I mean, we would expect, am I wrong in that kind of condition that we’re experiencing right now, wouldn’t we expect wages to really be being pushed right up?
I mean, if there’s that much demand for work overall, that would have this effect on wages, but we’re really not seeing that and what signs of growth we are seeing in wages are tepid. Is that right?
But that is potentially one of the mechanisms that is broken in the economy. I think one of the causes of measured low unemployment is that a lot of people have left the workforce and you can see that both at younger ages, people spending more time in school, people going back to school, people getting credentialized, and also at older ages, people finding ways to take what amounts to early retirement, or taking early retirement as opposed to waiting for full retirement. All of those mechanisms are eating away at the labor force from both ends of the age distribution, and even in the middle, you see people exiting the labor force for good, and becoming discouraged.
I think that matters a great deal for whether, to what extent monopsony is the ultimate cause of these problems, because monopsony’s a problem that would cause firms to demand fewer workers and thus, lower wages for the workers that they already have, and that could macro level, exactly be at the heart of these issues of, “Well, why has labor force participation seemingly declined among workers at every level of the labor market life cycle?”
What that means, in the nerdiest context, is that employers have power to set wages. In the standard, competitive model of the economy, individual firms do not have the power to either set prices in their market for their output, so that’s monopoly, nor do they have power to set wages in the market for one of their inputs, which is labor. They just go to the market and if they need a new worker, the market sets the price for that work.
When there’s monopsony power, firm’s decisions change because they affect the wages that all of their workers make when they decide to employ or not employ a worker at the margin. So, in the most orthodox model of labor market monopsony, firms will choose to hire fewer workers than they do in a competitive labor market, because of the effect that hiring fewer workers has on the wage that they pay to all of their workers.
That’s the fundamental story that’s going on not just in our paper, but in all of the theoretical work about why would we think that monopsony would have an effect on all of these labor market outcomes we’ve been talking about. Not just wages, but people exited the labor force, as you pointed out, the opioid crisis. Lots of what I would consider labor market pathologies can potentially be explained by widespread monopsony power.
This is kind of the same thing, but it’s about wages and what workers can get in the marketplace. So you’ve done together with a couple of other economists, Jose Azar and Ioana Marinescu, have done a couple of studies that really delve into this and have been getting a lot of attention and I want to talk a little bit about the first one that you did which came out back in December. I’ll say to listeners, you can go to the show page for this episode and we’ll post links to these studies and to the New York Times article, and you’ll find the show page at ILSR.org.
But starting with that first study, one of the most visually arresting maps I’ve seen in a while is in that study, and it’s this map of the United States broken up, I think by county, and it’s a measure of how concentrated the labor market is in each county. That is, the notion that if you’re in a particular occupation, there may only be one or two, or three companies within your commuting distance that you could apply to for work. It’s a highly concentrated market, so you use red to show extremely concentrated and most of the map is red.
And then, some other parts of it are orange and yellow, which are highly and moderately concentrated. That’s pretty much the rest of it, orange, yellow, and red. And then there are few islands of green. Those are unconcentrated markets, but they’re very few. It’s Minneapolis, Denver, Boston, Miami. It’s mostly cities. Then, just surrounded by this sea of highly concentrated labor markets.
Tell us a little bit about what’s behind this map. What kinds of occupations are you looking at? What does this really mean?
That’s a fairly rich dataset relative to the datasets that most labor economists are used to, because you can see at least some information about both employers and employees. So, the classical labor economics that I was referring to before where you study education, race, and gender, that’s because mostly for workers, you just see things about the worker, and also what they get paid, but you don’t see anything about their firm.
Here at least, we do see which firms are posting vacancies and where they’re located, and we can thereby create the map that you were just referring to. What we did is look at the occupations that arise most frequently in this database. I think it’s 20 of the most frequently appearing occupations, and we defined the labor market as the vacancies that are posted for those occupations within a given commuting zone, in a given quarter.
So, that is an important concept, market definition, especially if you’re doing antitrust type analysis, to see whether the market is concentrated or unconcentrated, and to what extent. We think that that market definition is not necessarily exactly the right market definition in every single case, but it is small C conservative, in the sense that when workers are looking for a job, they tend to look for jobs that they think they would have some chance of getting, and if you look at the occupation level that we look at, it’s actually wider than the set of jobs that workers would think they have some chance of getting, looking at that dataset from the perspective of which jobs do the workers actually apply to.
We’re including more job vacancy postings in our market definition than we think are really relevant to individual workers who are looking for a job, so that would tend to underestimate the degree of concentration in that labor market, and yet we still find the results that you refer to, which is that labor markets tends to be highly concentrated.
One last thing to note about how that chart is created, how that map is created, is this whole dataset is about job vacancy postings, insofar as economists have studied labor market concentration at all. Before, it tends to be the concentration of employment, and not the concentration of vacancies, and I think it is correct to look at concentration of vacancies if you can, as opposed to the concentration of employment, generally easier to get data on the concentration of employment, because what’s really relevant to workers who are looking for a job is how many firms are actually hiring.
And again, going back to the idea of pathologies of the labor market, one thing that we observe in this era of slack labor markets is that workers tend to stay in the same jobs for longer because they themselves cannot move up the job ladder as the metaphor that economists typically use, and the flip side of workers staying in the same side for longer and not moving up the job ladder is that any given job is vacated less frequently.
Even if say there’s a number of people currently working as a farm equipment mechanic in the area of Wisconsin, where Matt Gies works, that doesn’t necessarily mean that there are vacant jobs in that area that he can potentially apply to. That’s why I think we show a finding that caught a lot of people’s attention, because they tend to think like, “Oh, well every firm, not every firm has a farm equipment mechanic, but every firm has administrators and secretaries,” and certainly it seems like the healthcare sector employs a lot of people, so you would think that say the market for nurses is relatively unconcentrated, but no, that doesn’t necessarily mean that there are jobs available for people in all of these different occupations, especially not for people who are looking for a job.
There I think there are many fewer options to be had, and that’s why the finding of concentrated labor markets seems to ring so true with people.
Not our evidence. I think that there exists pretty strong circumstantial case that monopsony’s a bigger problem for lower skilled workers, and that’s exactly because they are “more interchangeable,” that their power is therefore diminished in the labor market and what makes workers ever get what they’re worth is the idea that they’re irreplaceable.
Our paper certainly doesn’t suggest that monopsony is a bigger problem for … I should say concentration is a bigger problem for highly skilled people, and in fact, there are occupations in our dataset that most, especially antitrust people, but really anybody who studies the occupational distribution of the labor market might think, “Well, concentration can’t really be a problem for secretaries or administrators or for people who seemingly have skills that are relatively interchangeable across employers.”
I think that’s just not borne out in the data, and the fact that it’s not borne out really should make people rethink their theory of how the labor market works, and how it is determined who gets what in the labor market.
As in any social science endeavor, you want to say, “Okay, well we have documented a concentration and wages, and now let’s see if we can be more robust in saying the variation in concentration causes a variation in wages,” and our estimate for the extent to which the variation in which concentration causes a variation in wages is that if you increase the level of concentration from the 25th percentile labor market to the 75th percentile labor market, you reduce wages by 17%.
But I think the way a layperson might look at that paper, but more generally the question of how big of a problem is monopsony in the labor market, is that you could see all of these different mechanics by which monopsony could affect wages, among other concentration, as not so easily separable. As a social scientist, you want to chop up the potential pathways of causation and say, “Well, this one, specifically concentration, has this estimated effect on wages.”
I think the more general policy question is to what degree does power on the part of employers affect wages? And there are multiple mechanisms by which that could affect wages. I mean, for one thing, let’s say that shareholders or firms are demanding that the firms that they own pay out more money to the shareholders and therefore hire fewer people. I would certainly think that that reflects the increasing power of employers versus employees.
It might have two different effects on the mechanism that we’re talking about. It might cause firms to post fewer vacancies, and it might also cause firms to pay lower wages, but in reality, both of those outcomes are the effect of the same cause, which is the different power that is held by the shareholders to extract what they can from the firm.
This whole long story is about trying to say, “Well, we might say that the point estimate is 17% but we’re trying to net out these other mechanisms that cause variation in concentration, and also cause variation in wages,” where it’s not the variation in concentration that causes the variation wages, but that doesn’t necessarily mean it’s not the rising power of employers that causes the variation in wages. I think that, there’s never going to be any one paper that tells you what the answer to that question is, but I think there’s a lot of research now that suggests that that is really crucial component of understanding what’s going on in the economy and in the labor market.
First of all, I want to thank all of you who made a donation at the end of the year to the Institute for Local Self-Reliance. Your financial support not only underwrites this podcast, keeping it ad free, but also helps us produce all the research and resources that we make available on our website, as well as all of the technical assistance that we provide to elected officials and citizens across the country.
Every year our small staff helps hundreds of communities challenge corporate concentration, and rebuild their local economies. So, please take a minute and go to ILSR.org, and click on the donate button if you haven’t. That’s ILSR.org, and if making a donation isn’t something you can do, please consider helping us in other ways.
One of the best things you can do to help us reach a wider audience with this podcast is to rate and review it on iTunes, Stitcher, or wherever you get your podcasts. That gives us a big boost in visibility, and it’s just hugely helpful when you do that, so thank you so much.
We’re back with Marshall Steinbaum, Research Director of the Roosevelt Institute, and we’re talking about concentration, and the ways in which corporate concentration is actually driving down wages and has really kept people who work for a living from earning what their should from their labors, and from all of the productivity increases in the economy.
Marshall, I want to turn to this question of like how, given what your research and the research of others is showing about these effects, what the answer is. I want to start with one potential answer that I’ve heard some people put out there, which is that workers should just move. We talked about the map and I was noting that there are a few, very few, green islands of actually competitive labor markets, mostly cities. Why don’t people in rural Wisconsin and Eastern Maine and Iowa and everywhere else just all move to Miami or Denver?
That is, they want to stay as close as possible to where they originate, and the idea that the economy consists of workers who are highly mobile, any place is on the table, and in particular, if they’re not doing well in the labor market right now, that’s because they’re just unwilling to take the risk, take the plunge necessary and go to a place where they could definitely find a job. That’s just a wrong understanding of how people live their lives, and how people’s work interacts with the rest of their lives.
People don’t want to move. They want to be able to have a job where they live, and it’s not so easy to move because most people get their jobs from their family or their professional network, or I should say their social network, and to say, “Well, leave all that behind and just go to some city where you’ve never lived and you’ll be fine there,” that’s just not true for people. They’re not going to just have a job land in their lap.
I mean certainly if you have a family, you’re not going to take the risk of going some place where you don’t have a job and not being able to support them, and have them live, you’re going to stay where you have a social network and potential family to help you out with all of the things that are necessary in life.
Not only is it just not true that workers move very much. They’ve been moving less and less since 2000, and I would say again that that reflects these labor market pathologies. It is one of the pathologies of the labor market. Moving is something that workers do when they have a job offer that actually makes it okay, makes it worthwhile for them to take the plunge and leave their social network, or because it’s their social network that was actually able to come up with the job offer, even if it’s at some geographic distance from where they currently originate.
It’s indeed a problem that geographic mobility is on the decline, but that’s not a problem that individual workers aren’t doing what they should. It’s a problem that is part of the larger problem of economists and policymakers just not understanding how to do their job.
I think that is again, also overly simplified, and misunderstanding why it is that house prices are high in San Francisco, and what the effect of a policy that would totally deregulate say the housing market in San Francisco, I think that would most likely increase the market power of incumbent owners of housing and of land in San Francisco, and possibly even increase rental costs to the people. That’s more speculative, but it’s certainly not some sort of policy panacea that you could just cause a bonanza of building and construction, that would suddenly bring the place of living in San Francisco down to the level of the rent of living in a much more rural and less densely populated area.
You’ve been among, along with others, been advocating that some of the labor market effects ought to be part of how we think about antitrust, how we think about mergers. Tell me a little bit about what that would actually mean. How would you implement that kind of set of ideas in the context of antitrust policy?
There are some non-merger cases that at least the federal antitrust agencies undertake, but I would say that’s probably the bulk of their work is reviewing the mergers where two companies say, “Okay, well we want to merge” and the agencies either say, “We have no problem with that” or they bring a case and demand concessions, or even go to trial, as it happening now in AT&T/Time Warner.
The key economic analysis that’s undertaken as part of merger review is to deduce whether the merger of two competing companies in a given market would cause prices to go up or down, and that requires defining what the relevant market is for the parties to the merger.
As you’ve just correctly said, that is in the present time, more or less solely done on the basis of monopoly and pricing of output goods, and it is quite likely that the labor markets are defined fundamentally differently from product markets.
If you think of something like the Maytag/Whirlpool merger that happened in the mid 2000s, that was basically the two major home appliance manufacturers merged. They were allowed to merge unchallenged. I think there’s good evidence to suggest that that merger turned out to be anti-competitive after the fact, in the market for washing machines, dishwashers, other appliances that they produced.
At the time, I would bet that the authorities defined the market for washing machines and other home appliances as being the entire United States, or maybe something slightly less than that. But the point is, everyone gets their washing machine. They might shop for it retail, but there’s a distribution network that is essentially geographically unbounded.
Whereas for labor, the whole point of what we’ve been talking about, and certainly of our paper, is that the market for labor is quite a bit geographically determined. If that merger had been evaluated for its labor market impact, you would have seen the whole economy wide market for washing machines is not going to become less concentrated as a result of this merger.
I mean again, I don’t think that turned out to be correct, but I think that was probably the finding that the agencies came up with, but the labor market for workers at the factories where those companies worked are very likely to get more concentrated, and I think we know for a fact that a couple of factories at one or the other parties was closed directly as a result of that merger, and a lot of people were laid off.
Under the present implementation on antitrust policy, those layoffs and closure of factories would be put forward as an efficiency gained from the merger, because the parties would say, “Well, we’re concentrating our production at our most efficient factories, and this will actually end up benefiting consumers, because we’ll be able to lower prices, as a result of the fact that our production chain is more efficient.” But if you, again, analyze the merger from the perspective of labor market, then what looks like an efficiency is actually just a monopsonization of the local labor market and consequently would be viewed as anti-competitive.
That is but one of the areas in which antitrust policy could change as a result of taking labor markets seriously. There’s been a policy interest in curtailing the use of restrictive labor market agreements, so this would be in the realm of antitrust conduct, not of market structure. Things like no poaching agreements, and noncompete closes.
So, no poaching agreements are the parties are employers, and they would be agreeing to not hire one another workers. That is clearly already against the law, because it’s a horizontal cartel basically, in the labor market, and what movement there is to change the law with respect to no poaching agreements pertains to the use of them in franchising contracts.
So, say two McDonald’s franchisees or any McDonald’s franchisee in the contract it signs with the McDonald’s headquarters will say, “Well, we’re not going to hire the employees of another McDonald’s franchisee.” It’s unclear whether that’s a horizontal or a vertical agreement, but in any case, there’s a policy proposal from Senator Cory Booker to make that also illegal, which is good.
On noncompete clauses, that is an agreement between an employer and an employee for the employee not to work for a different company if they leave their current one. That is more controversial as a matter of antitrust law, because since the takeover of antitrust law by the Chicago School, vertical non-price agreements, that is imposing terms of any contract on the counterparty, is viewed as procompetitve, so if antitrust law were to move to treating noncompete clauses in the labor market as illegal, then that would just be a pretty major departure from existing policy, at least vis-a-vis labor. I’m sorry, vis-a-vis antitrust. Vis-a-vis labor may be more in the spirit of existing labor market policies.
The final point I want to make is a big economic theoretical point, which is that our findings, both in the CareerBuilder paper, and especially in our more recent paper that uses a larger dataset of essentially all online vacancy postings, in that paper we do more of an analysis of what is the right market definition for labor markets? We come to the conclusion, as I was discussing previously, that this occupation by commuting zone by quarter is actually fairly conservative because that overestimates the number of alternatives that are really functionally available to most workers if they’re looking for a job.
Based on our analysis in this paper, and from some other work in the literature, it looks like the right labor market definition is more along the lines of individual firms. That means that for every single firm in the economy, or under this theory, most firms in the economy, have a sufficient amount of wage setting discretion that is monopsony power, such that they are monopsonists in the market for their own workers’ labor. If every firm is a monopsony, then what you’re looking at in extreme antitrust policy world is that every firm should be broken up.
That is not really a feasible antitrust policy. What that suggests is rather that antitrust can do a lot in the labor market to make it more competitive, and it’s absolutely appropriate to talk about things like merger review on the basis of labor market definition, and that takes wage reduction seriously as a potential threat of anti-competitive conduct.
But antitrust alone cannot solve the labor market’s problems, and specifically the wage setting power of employers or just employer power more generally. This is why historically we have had labor market regulations, why we have protections for collective bargaining, because we recognize that the employer/employee relationship is inherently one of unequal power.
Whereas, the premise in antitrust is more or less that you have parties with equal power and then you try to correct the market imperfections, such that where one party becomes overwhelmingly powerful, you pair it back, their power, and limit it in such a way as they can exert it to distort markets completely and remove competition. In labor markets, we already know that one party’s going to be more powerful than its employers, so we have a whole realm of policy that is labor and employment policy, and collective bargaining, and unionization rights. All of those are necessary to restore a proper degree of balance to the economy. Antitrust alone is not going to be able to do it.
There are all kinds of ways in which policy needs to help ensure that people have a fair playing field when they’re bargaining as workers. We see this in other sectors, too. We’ve done a lot of work on dairy farms, for example. If you have a very perishable product which is fresh milk, and it’s very bulky, and you can’t ship it very far away before it goes bad, you’re really hamstrung. It’s hard to bargain with the milk process, and so we’ve always supported this history of federal and regional pricing supports in the milk industry, because it just really is inherently not the kind of competition, doesn’t produce enough competition for milk.
The second thing you mentioned was around these noncompete clauses and these poaching agreements which are just we should have you or someone else on the show at some point to talk more in depth about this, because it’s just so scandalous to me that you’re a fast food worker, and you can’t go take a job at a different McDonald’s, or at another fast food outlet, because you’ve signed this agreement or there’s a no poaching deal.
We could take some direct action using competition policy against those kinds of things, and then the first one you mentioned was around mergers, and this idea of having these labor effects and these labor markets being considered in the context of mergers. I have a question that I want to ask you about that to wrap things up here. Historically antitrust was as much about people as producers of value as workers, as it was about us as consumers.
John Sherman, who lent his name to the very first or one of the first antitrust laws back in 1890 said monopoly is a problem because, “It commands the price of labor without fear of strikes, for in its field, it allows no competitors.” Clearly this issue that you’re talking about has always been there from the beginning, and the question I have for you is how we should think about this. It relates to a really interesting blog post that I read, that Lina Khan wrote recently for a European outlet about … Lina is the Legal Policy Director at the Open Markets Institute.
She was writing about this new movement for a better antitrust, and what should be the principles of it. We’ll post a link to this on the show page, but one of the things she talks about is this idea that antitrust went wrong because we really collapsed everything to this single outcome, which is lower consumer prices. We should be careful, she says, not to collapse everything to other sets of outcomes, like for example, labor effects, that really we need to think about antitrust in terms of using it to structure markets.
What we should be doing is asking, “Does a merger create a market where there’s a lot of … Does it reduce competition too much?” How many competitors are there in this market? Is it a market where it’s easy for a new entrant to come in, a new business to come in? We really should be looking more at structure and not at outcomes, and even if we switch from a consumer outcome to a different outcome, we may be not in really a better place in the long run.
I wanted to ask you a little bit about how you think about that, particularly in the context of these labor issues?
I would say we, for ideological reasons, developed the view that the economy structures itself, and hence the sphere in which that policy can affect is relatively narrow, and is about correcting minor deviations from the optimal structure of the economy and where the just field of operations and the field of which policy can affect is constrained from the outset.
Whereas, when antitrust was invented and brought certainly to the federal level, in which there absolutely were economists there at the birth part of the debate about what was the role of this policy alongside other policies like regulation, natural monopolies, utilities, and labor policies. I mean, taxation more broadly, it was that the role of economic policy was to structure the economy. It was up to us to decide what economy we wanted to live in and how it was going to work.
Or, we could just let the big businesses decide, let the powerful decide it. I think there’s a great quote in the book “Social Control of Business” by the economist John Maurice Clark that says the key question is, are we going to let big business control us or are we going to control them? 10 words that are an extremely pithy and absolutely on point summary of the issue that faces us with respect to antitrust and all these other policy areas, and that also point to where economics as a field went wrong, and where just overall policy making has shrunk to a shriveled bare imitation of its former self, in terms of what its ambitions were and what was on the table.
I think that given that it’s now a matter of consensus or nearing consensus that the economy that we live in is not functioning well to the benefit of all, and that really we went wrong somewhere, even if you don’t agree with me that antitrust is a big component of where we went wrong, I think it’s a little hard to deny that economic outcomes are not what they should be.
This whole idea that we really lost something profound and need to win it back I think is going to become a lot more attractive beyond the set of relatively small people like me and Lina who are really focused on this issue of antitrust policy and what the point of that is.
He had seen enough of the move to an active antitrust policy in the second half of the new deal to have something to say about that by the 1939 republication. He also has a lot of very interesting comments about the relationship between what we now call macroeconomic policy or macroeconomics in general, and antitrust and market structure. This is a confluence that has not had a lot of interest from economists in the intervening period up until right now.
I would say now there are papers being published that have that flavor to them, but I think that Clark was absolutely on point in terms of trying to locate the ultimate causes for both macroeconomic failures that happened in The Great Depression, and also why what we might think of a Keynesian macroeconomic policy is a good idea, given how much market power is just a pervasive fact about the economy and how big business and its structure, and market concentration give rise to macro phenomena that Keynes and his contemporaries were concerned about.
That is just, it’s a fantastic book. He covers a ton of ground, and it is, I mean maybe it’s especially meaningful to me ’cause I know how thin and pale and pathetic most economics publications are in the intervening 70 years since Clark was writing, but it certainly makes me think that we went seriously awry somewhere along the way, and we need to rediscover the spirit of John Maurice Clark.
Once again, please help us out by rating this podcast and sharing it with your friends. This show is produced by Lisa Gonzalez and Nick Stumo-Langer. Our theme music is Funk Interlude by Dysfunction_AL. For the Institute for Local Self-Reliance, I’m Stacy Mitchell. I hope you’ll join us again in two weeks for the next episode of Building Local Power.
Like this episode? Please help us reach a wider audience by rating Building Local Power on iTunes or wherever you find your podcasts. And please become a subscriber! If you missed our previous episodes make sure to bookmark our Building Local Power Podcast Homepage.
If you have show ideas or comments, please email us at [email protected]. Also, join the conversation by talking about #BuildingLocalPower on Twitter and Facebook!
Audio Credit: Funk Interlude by Dysfunction_AL Ft: Fourstones – Scomber (Bonus Track). Copyright 2016 Licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial (3.0) license.
Photo Credit: Fibonacci Blue via Flickr.
Follow the Institute for Local Self-Reliance on Twitter and Facebook and, for monthly updates on our work, sign-up for our ILSR general newsletter.
4.9
9595 ratings
If unemployment is so low, why aren’t workers getting cut in on the deal? That’s a question that our guest, economist Marshall Steinbaum, has been trying to answer. In a new study, which was featured in the New York Times, Steinbaum and his co-authors find that one of the main reasons that wages have not kept pace is that most local labor markets are highly concentrated. Only a few companies are hiring and, as a result, these dominant firms have the power to set wages below the rate that people would earn in a more competitive labor market.
(The technical term for this is “monopsony,” a close cousin of monopoly, which refers to a situation in which a buyer — of labor, in this case — has the power to dictate the price.)
Steinbaum, who’s Research Director at the Roosevelt Institute, joins Building Local Power host and ILSR co-director Stacy Mitchell to discuss his research and how elected officials can fix the broken market for labor.
Photo Courtesy of Roosevelt Institute
Our guest, Marshall Steinbaum, provided a book recommendation, and we’ll also share some of his original research:
Map courtesy of The Roosevelt Institute with this caption: “A map of the average concentration of the 200 occupations that appear most frequently in the Burning Glass data, by Commuting Zone.”
Gies grew up on a farm and he spent a lot of time as a kid tinkering with farm equipment. When he grew up, he decided to become a farm equipment mechanic, repairing tractors and the like, and he really loved the work. He worked for a John Deere dealership, owned by a Wisconsin company called Riesterer & Schnell, which owns 12 different John Deere dealerships across Wisconsin.
But Gies actually left that job because he said they demanded far too many hours of work for too little pay, so three years ago he quit. The problem is that all these years later, despite being surrounded by farms, and despite looking for work, he hasn’t been able to find another job repairing farm equipment. Most of the seven John Deere dealerships within an hour’s drive of his house are actually owned by Riesterer & Schnell, the same company that he left.
They have a monopoly on the supply of jobs repairing farm equipment. It turns out that this is a common situation in most regions of country. Many occupations are dominated by just a few employers at most. As a result, there’s no real competition for labor. Economists have recently began to study this problem and what they’re finding is quite striking. Concentration has played a significant role in holding down wages over the last 20 years. It’s one of the key reasons American workers have not gotten a raise, even as productivity has soared.
Today on the show, our guest is Marshall Steinbaum, one of the economists whose been at the forefront of this research and whose work was featured in that New York Times story. Marshall is Research Director at the Roosevelt Institute. Marshall, welcome to the show.
Even as the economy grows, there’s an equal division of the pie among the owners of labor and capital over time, and consequently, the total absolute amount that’s going to workers would be rising over time as the economy gets larger.
What has been going on now since 2000 at least is that the share of the pie that goes to workers has been in decline, and it’s been in decline in a very specific way. That share of the pie declines when there’s been a recession, as there was in 2000-2001, and then again in the Great Recession, starting in 2008. And then, it’s basically flat during the resulting recovery that follows the recession.
That is the phenomenon that I think is getting increasing attention from labor economists, because it cannot be explained by any of the data, by any of the observables that economists would typically think of as causing long run changes in wages for individuals, and for the economy as a whole. Notably, that would be education, so the view among economists is that what determines how much individual workers get over the course of their lives is what their skills are, and you can tell what their skills are from their level of education and their level of experience in the labor market.
Increasingly, education is just not a very good way of discerning who gets what in the labor market. We had already known this before my paper came out, about monopsony specifically, because there’s an increasing inequality in interfirm earnings among workers. What that means is the company you work for matters more in determining your wages than it previously did. Rather than it be your own qualities, your own data that’s like education and race or gender, that is relevant to knowing what your total income is, it matters more who you work for and their position in the economy, and their position vis-a-vis workers.
I think that had already primed the economics scholarly community to look for explanations for who gets what that are at odds with received wisdom, at least as its existed for the last couple of decades in economics.
But then what’s been really unusual is that in the recovery periods, workers are not seeing their wages go up. And I think most people who are listening will recognize that problem maybe in their own lives. What’s really striking right now is I think, if I read this correctly, unemployment is now at a 17 year low. I mean, we would expect, am I wrong in that kind of condition that we’re experiencing right now, wouldn’t we expect wages to really be being pushed right up?
I mean, if there’s that much demand for work overall, that would have this effect on wages, but we’re really not seeing that and what signs of growth we are seeing in wages are tepid. Is that right?
But that is potentially one of the mechanisms that is broken in the economy. I think one of the causes of measured low unemployment is that a lot of people have left the workforce and you can see that both at younger ages, people spending more time in school, people going back to school, people getting credentialized, and also at older ages, people finding ways to take what amounts to early retirement, or taking early retirement as opposed to waiting for full retirement. All of those mechanisms are eating away at the labor force from both ends of the age distribution, and even in the middle, you see people exiting the labor force for good, and becoming discouraged.
I think that matters a great deal for whether, to what extent monopsony is the ultimate cause of these problems, because monopsony’s a problem that would cause firms to demand fewer workers and thus, lower wages for the workers that they already have, and that could macro level, exactly be at the heart of these issues of, “Well, why has labor force participation seemingly declined among workers at every level of the labor market life cycle?”
What that means, in the nerdiest context, is that employers have power to set wages. In the standard, competitive model of the economy, individual firms do not have the power to either set prices in their market for their output, so that’s monopoly, nor do they have power to set wages in the market for one of their inputs, which is labor. They just go to the market and if they need a new worker, the market sets the price for that work.
When there’s monopsony power, firm’s decisions change because they affect the wages that all of their workers make when they decide to employ or not employ a worker at the margin. So, in the most orthodox model of labor market monopsony, firms will choose to hire fewer workers than they do in a competitive labor market, because of the effect that hiring fewer workers has on the wage that they pay to all of their workers.
That’s the fundamental story that’s going on not just in our paper, but in all of the theoretical work about why would we think that monopsony would have an effect on all of these labor market outcomes we’ve been talking about. Not just wages, but people exited the labor force, as you pointed out, the opioid crisis. Lots of what I would consider labor market pathologies can potentially be explained by widespread monopsony power.
This is kind of the same thing, but it’s about wages and what workers can get in the marketplace. So you’ve done together with a couple of other economists, Jose Azar and Ioana Marinescu, have done a couple of studies that really delve into this and have been getting a lot of attention and I want to talk a little bit about the first one that you did which came out back in December. I’ll say to listeners, you can go to the show page for this episode and we’ll post links to these studies and to the New York Times article, and you’ll find the show page at ILSR.org.
But starting with that first study, one of the most visually arresting maps I’ve seen in a while is in that study, and it’s this map of the United States broken up, I think by county, and it’s a measure of how concentrated the labor market is in each county. That is, the notion that if you’re in a particular occupation, there may only be one or two, or three companies within your commuting distance that you could apply to for work. It’s a highly concentrated market, so you use red to show extremely concentrated and most of the map is red.
And then, some other parts of it are orange and yellow, which are highly and moderately concentrated. That’s pretty much the rest of it, orange, yellow, and red. And then there are few islands of green. Those are unconcentrated markets, but they’re very few. It’s Minneapolis, Denver, Boston, Miami. It’s mostly cities. Then, just surrounded by this sea of highly concentrated labor markets.
Tell us a little bit about what’s behind this map. What kinds of occupations are you looking at? What does this really mean?
That’s a fairly rich dataset relative to the datasets that most labor economists are used to, because you can see at least some information about both employers and employees. So, the classical labor economics that I was referring to before where you study education, race, and gender, that’s because mostly for workers, you just see things about the worker, and also what they get paid, but you don’t see anything about their firm.
Here at least, we do see which firms are posting vacancies and where they’re located, and we can thereby create the map that you were just referring to. What we did is look at the occupations that arise most frequently in this database. I think it’s 20 of the most frequently appearing occupations, and we defined the labor market as the vacancies that are posted for those occupations within a given commuting zone, in a given quarter.
So, that is an important concept, market definition, especially if you’re doing antitrust type analysis, to see whether the market is concentrated or unconcentrated, and to what extent. We think that that market definition is not necessarily exactly the right market definition in every single case, but it is small C conservative, in the sense that when workers are looking for a job, they tend to look for jobs that they think they would have some chance of getting, and if you look at the occupation level that we look at, it’s actually wider than the set of jobs that workers would think they have some chance of getting, looking at that dataset from the perspective of which jobs do the workers actually apply to.
We’re including more job vacancy postings in our market definition than we think are really relevant to individual workers who are looking for a job, so that would tend to underestimate the degree of concentration in that labor market, and yet we still find the results that you refer to, which is that labor markets tends to be highly concentrated.
One last thing to note about how that chart is created, how that map is created, is this whole dataset is about job vacancy postings, insofar as economists have studied labor market concentration at all. Before, it tends to be the concentration of employment, and not the concentration of vacancies, and I think it is correct to look at concentration of vacancies if you can, as opposed to the concentration of employment, generally easier to get data on the concentration of employment, because what’s really relevant to workers who are looking for a job is how many firms are actually hiring.
And again, going back to the idea of pathologies of the labor market, one thing that we observe in this era of slack labor markets is that workers tend to stay in the same jobs for longer because they themselves cannot move up the job ladder as the metaphor that economists typically use, and the flip side of workers staying in the same side for longer and not moving up the job ladder is that any given job is vacated less frequently.
Even if say there’s a number of people currently working as a farm equipment mechanic in the area of Wisconsin, where Matt Gies works, that doesn’t necessarily mean that there are vacant jobs in that area that he can potentially apply to. That’s why I think we show a finding that caught a lot of people’s attention, because they tend to think like, “Oh, well every firm, not every firm has a farm equipment mechanic, but every firm has administrators and secretaries,” and certainly it seems like the healthcare sector employs a lot of people, so you would think that say the market for nurses is relatively unconcentrated, but no, that doesn’t necessarily mean that there are jobs available for people in all of these different occupations, especially not for people who are looking for a job.
There I think there are many fewer options to be had, and that’s why the finding of concentrated labor markets seems to ring so true with people.
Not our evidence. I think that there exists pretty strong circumstantial case that monopsony’s a bigger problem for lower skilled workers, and that’s exactly because they are “more interchangeable,” that their power is therefore diminished in the labor market and what makes workers ever get what they’re worth is the idea that they’re irreplaceable.
Our paper certainly doesn’t suggest that monopsony is a bigger problem for … I should say concentration is a bigger problem for highly skilled people, and in fact, there are occupations in our dataset that most, especially antitrust people, but really anybody who studies the occupational distribution of the labor market might think, “Well, concentration can’t really be a problem for secretaries or administrators or for people who seemingly have skills that are relatively interchangeable across employers.”
I think that’s just not borne out in the data, and the fact that it’s not borne out really should make people rethink their theory of how the labor market works, and how it is determined who gets what in the labor market.
As in any social science endeavor, you want to say, “Okay, well we have documented a concentration and wages, and now let’s see if we can be more robust in saying the variation in concentration causes a variation in wages,” and our estimate for the extent to which the variation in which concentration causes a variation in wages is that if you increase the level of concentration from the 25th percentile labor market to the 75th percentile labor market, you reduce wages by 17%.
But I think the way a layperson might look at that paper, but more generally the question of how big of a problem is monopsony in the labor market, is that you could see all of these different mechanics by which monopsony could affect wages, among other concentration, as not so easily separable. As a social scientist, you want to chop up the potential pathways of causation and say, “Well, this one, specifically concentration, has this estimated effect on wages.”
I think the more general policy question is to what degree does power on the part of employers affect wages? And there are multiple mechanisms by which that could affect wages. I mean, for one thing, let’s say that shareholders or firms are demanding that the firms that they own pay out more money to the shareholders and therefore hire fewer people. I would certainly think that that reflects the increasing power of employers versus employees.
It might have two different effects on the mechanism that we’re talking about. It might cause firms to post fewer vacancies, and it might also cause firms to pay lower wages, but in reality, both of those outcomes are the effect of the same cause, which is the different power that is held by the shareholders to extract what they can from the firm.
This whole long story is about trying to say, “Well, we might say that the point estimate is 17% but we’re trying to net out these other mechanisms that cause variation in concentration, and also cause variation in wages,” where it’s not the variation in concentration that causes the variation wages, but that doesn’t necessarily mean it’s not the rising power of employers that causes the variation in wages. I think that, there’s never going to be any one paper that tells you what the answer to that question is, but I think there’s a lot of research now that suggests that that is really crucial component of understanding what’s going on in the economy and in the labor market.
First of all, I want to thank all of you who made a donation at the end of the year to the Institute for Local Self-Reliance. Your financial support not only underwrites this podcast, keeping it ad free, but also helps us produce all the research and resources that we make available on our website, as well as all of the technical assistance that we provide to elected officials and citizens across the country.
Every year our small staff helps hundreds of communities challenge corporate concentration, and rebuild their local economies. So, please take a minute and go to ILSR.org, and click on the donate button if you haven’t. That’s ILSR.org, and if making a donation isn’t something you can do, please consider helping us in other ways.
One of the best things you can do to help us reach a wider audience with this podcast is to rate and review it on iTunes, Stitcher, or wherever you get your podcasts. That gives us a big boost in visibility, and it’s just hugely helpful when you do that, so thank you so much.
We’re back with Marshall Steinbaum, Research Director of the Roosevelt Institute, and we’re talking about concentration, and the ways in which corporate concentration is actually driving down wages and has really kept people who work for a living from earning what their should from their labors, and from all of the productivity increases in the economy.
Marshall, I want to turn to this question of like how, given what your research and the research of others is showing about these effects, what the answer is. I want to start with one potential answer that I’ve heard some people put out there, which is that workers should just move. We talked about the map and I was noting that there are a few, very few, green islands of actually competitive labor markets, mostly cities. Why don’t people in rural Wisconsin and Eastern Maine and Iowa and everywhere else just all move to Miami or Denver?
That is, they want to stay as close as possible to where they originate, and the idea that the economy consists of workers who are highly mobile, any place is on the table, and in particular, if they’re not doing well in the labor market right now, that’s because they’re just unwilling to take the risk, take the plunge necessary and go to a place where they could definitely find a job. That’s just a wrong understanding of how people live their lives, and how people’s work interacts with the rest of their lives.
People don’t want to move. They want to be able to have a job where they live, and it’s not so easy to move because most people get their jobs from their family or their professional network, or I should say their social network, and to say, “Well, leave all that behind and just go to some city where you’ve never lived and you’ll be fine there,” that’s just not true for people. They’re not going to just have a job land in their lap.
I mean certainly if you have a family, you’re not going to take the risk of going some place where you don’t have a job and not being able to support them, and have them live, you’re going to stay where you have a social network and potential family to help you out with all of the things that are necessary in life.
Not only is it just not true that workers move very much. They’ve been moving less and less since 2000, and I would say again that that reflects these labor market pathologies. It is one of the pathologies of the labor market. Moving is something that workers do when they have a job offer that actually makes it okay, makes it worthwhile for them to take the plunge and leave their social network, or because it’s their social network that was actually able to come up with the job offer, even if it’s at some geographic distance from where they currently originate.
It’s indeed a problem that geographic mobility is on the decline, but that’s not a problem that individual workers aren’t doing what they should. It’s a problem that is part of the larger problem of economists and policymakers just not understanding how to do their job.
I think that is again, also overly simplified, and misunderstanding why it is that house prices are high in San Francisco, and what the effect of a policy that would totally deregulate say the housing market in San Francisco, I think that would most likely increase the market power of incumbent owners of housing and of land in San Francisco, and possibly even increase rental costs to the people. That’s more speculative, but it’s certainly not some sort of policy panacea that you could just cause a bonanza of building and construction, that would suddenly bring the place of living in San Francisco down to the level of the rent of living in a much more rural and less densely populated area.
You’ve been among, along with others, been advocating that some of the labor market effects ought to be part of how we think about antitrust, how we think about mergers. Tell me a little bit about what that would actually mean. How would you implement that kind of set of ideas in the context of antitrust policy?
There are some non-merger cases that at least the federal antitrust agencies undertake, but I would say that’s probably the bulk of their work is reviewing the mergers where two companies say, “Okay, well we want to merge” and the agencies either say, “We have no problem with that” or they bring a case and demand concessions, or even go to trial, as it happening now in AT&T/Time Warner.
The key economic analysis that’s undertaken as part of merger review is to deduce whether the merger of two competing companies in a given market would cause prices to go up or down, and that requires defining what the relevant market is for the parties to the merger.
As you’ve just correctly said, that is in the present time, more or less solely done on the basis of monopoly and pricing of output goods, and it is quite likely that the labor markets are defined fundamentally differently from product markets.
If you think of something like the Maytag/Whirlpool merger that happened in the mid 2000s, that was basically the two major home appliance manufacturers merged. They were allowed to merge unchallenged. I think there’s good evidence to suggest that that merger turned out to be anti-competitive after the fact, in the market for washing machines, dishwashers, other appliances that they produced.
At the time, I would bet that the authorities defined the market for washing machines and other home appliances as being the entire United States, or maybe something slightly less than that. But the point is, everyone gets their washing machine. They might shop for it retail, but there’s a distribution network that is essentially geographically unbounded.
Whereas for labor, the whole point of what we’ve been talking about, and certainly of our paper, is that the market for labor is quite a bit geographically determined. If that merger had been evaluated for its labor market impact, you would have seen the whole economy wide market for washing machines is not going to become less concentrated as a result of this merger.
I mean again, I don’t think that turned out to be correct, but I think that was probably the finding that the agencies came up with, but the labor market for workers at the factories where those companies worked are very likely to get more concentrated, and I think we know for a fact that a couple of factories at one or the other parties was closed directly as a result of that merger, and a lot of people were laid off.
Under the present implementation on antitrust policy, those layoffs and closure of factories would be put forward as an efficiency gained from the merger, because the parties would say, “Well, we’re concentrating our production at our most efficient factories, and this will actually end up benefiting consumers, because we’ll be able to lower prices, as a result of the fact that our production chain is more efficient.” But if you, again, analyze the merger from the perspective of labor market, then what looks like an efficiency is actually just a monopsonization of the local labor market and consequently would be viewed as anti-competitive.
That is but one of the areas in which antitrust policy could change as a result of taking labor markets seriously. There’s been a policy interest in curtailing the use of restrictive labor market agreements, so this would be in the realm of antitrust conduct, not of market structure. Things like no poaching agreements, and noncompete closes.
So, no poaching agreements are the parties are employers, and they would be agreeing to not hire one another workers. That is clearly already against the law, because it’s a horizontal cartel basically, in the labor market, and what movement there is to change the law with respect to no poaching agreements pertains to the use of them in franchising contracts.
So, say two McDonald’s franchisees or any McDonald’s franchisee in the contract it signs with the McDonald’s headquarters will say, “Well, we’re not going to hire the employees of another McDonald’s franchisee.” It’s unclear whether that’s a horizontal or a vertical agreement, but in any case, there’s a policy proposal from Senator Cory Booker to make that also illegal, which is good.
On noncompete clauses, that is an agreement between an employer and an employee for the employee not to work for a different company if they leave their current one. That is more controversial as a matter of antitrust law, because since the takeover of antitrust law by the Chicago School, vertical non-price agreements, that is imposing terms of any contract on the counterparty, is viewed as procompetitve, so if antitrust law were to move to treating noncompete clauses in the labor market as illegal, then that would just be a pretty major departure from existing policy, at least vis-a-vis labor. I’m sorry, vis-a-vis antitrust. Vis-a-vis labor may be more in the spirit of existing labor market policies.
The final point I want to make is a big economic theoretical point, which is that our findings, both in the CareerBuilder paper, and especially in our more recent paper that uses a larger dataset of essentially all online vacancy postings, in that paper we do more of an analysis of what is the right market definition for labor markets? We come to the conclusion, as I was discussing previously, that this occupation by commuting zone by quarter is actually fairly conservative because that overestimates the number of alternatives that are really functionally available to most workers if they’re looking for a job.
Based on our analysis in this paper, and from some other work in the literature, it looks like the right labor market definition is more along the lines of individual firms. That means that for every single firm in the economy, or under this theory, most firms in the economy, have a sufficient amount of wage setting discretion that is monopsony power, such that they are monopsonists in the market for their own workers’ labor. If every firm is a monopsony, then what you’re looking at in extreme antitrust policy world is that every firm should be broken up.
That is not really a feasible antitrust policy. What that suggests is rather that antitrust can do a lot in the labor market to make it more competitive, and it’s absolutely appropriate to talk about things like merger review on the basis of labor market definition, and that takes wage reduction seriously as a potential threat of anti-competitive conduct.
But antitrust alone cannot solve the labor market’s problems, and specifically the wage setting power of employers or just employer power more generally. This is why historically we have had labor market regulations, why we have protections for collective bargaining, because we recognize that the employer/employee relationship is inherently one of unequal power.
Whereas, the premise in antitrust is more or less that you have parties with equal power and then you try to correct the market imperfections, such that where one party becomes overwhelmingly powerful, you pair it back, their power, and limit it in such a way as they can exert it to distort markets completely and remove competition. In labor markets, we already know that one party’s going to be more powerful than its employers, so we have a whole realm of policy that is labor and employment policy, and collective bargaining, and unionization rights. All of those are necessary to restore a proper degree of balance to the economy. Antitrust alone is not going to be able to do it.
There are all kinds of ways in which policy needs to help ensure that people have a fair playing field when they’re bargaining as workers. We see this in other sectors, too. We’ve done a lot of work on dairy farms, for example. If you have a very perishable product which is fresh milk, and it’s very bulky, and you can’t ship it very far away before it goes bad, you’re really hamstrung. It’s hard to bargain with the milk process, and so we’ve always supported this history of federal and regional pricing supports in the milk industry, because it just really is inherently not the kind of competition, doesn’t produce enough competition for milk.
The second thing you mentioned was around these noncompete clauses and these poaching agreements which are just we should have you or someone else on the show at some point to talk more in depth about this, because it’s just so scandalous to me that you’re a fast food worker, and you can’t go take a job at a different McDonald’s, or at another fast food outlet, because you’ve signed this agreement or there’s a no poaching deal.
We could take some direct action using competition policy against those kinds of things, and then the first one you mentioned was around mergers, and this idea of having these labor effects and these labor markets being considered in the context of mergers. I have a question that I want to ask you about that to wrap things up here. Historically antitrust was as much about people as producers of value as workers, as it was about us as consumers.
John Sherman, who lent his name to the very first or one of the first antitrust laws back in 1890 said monopoly is a problem because, “It commands the price of labor without fear of strikes, for in its field, it allows no competitors.” Clearly this issue that you’re talking about has always been there from the beginning, and the question I have for you is how we should think about this. It relates to a really interesting blog post that I read, that Lina Khan wrote recently for a European outlet about … Lina is the Legal Policy Director at the Open Markets Institute.
She was writing about this new movement for a better antitrust, and what should be the principles of it. We’ll post a link to this on the show page, but one of the things she talks about is this idea that antitrust went wrong because we really collapsed everything to this single outcome, which is lower consumer prices. We should be careful, she says, not to collapse everything to other sets of outcomes, like for example, labor effects, that really we need to think about antitrust in terms of using it to structure markets.
What we should be doing is asking, “Does a merger create a market where there’s a lot of … Does it reduce competition too much?” How many competitors are there in this market? Is it a market where it’s easy for a new entrant to come in, a new business to come in? We really should be looking more at structure and not at outcomes, and even if we switch from a consumer outcome to a different outcome, we may be not in really a better place in the long run.
I wanted to ask you a little bit about how you think about that, particularly in the context of these labor issues?
I would say we, for ideological reasons, developed the view that the economy structures itself, and hence the sphere in which that policy can affect is relatively narrow, and is about correcting minor deviations from the optimal structure of the economy and where the just field of operations and the field of which policy can affect is constrained from the outset.
Whereas, when antitrust was invented and brought certainly to the federal level, in which there absolutely were economists there at the birth part of the debate about what was the role of this policy alongside other policies like regulation, natural monopolies, utilities, and labor policies. I mean, taxation more broadly, it was that the role of economic policy was to structure the economy. It was up to us to decide what economy we wanted to live in and how it was going to work.
Or, we could just let the big businesses decide, let the powerful decide it. I think there’s a great quote in the book “Social Control of Business” by the economist John Maurice Clark that says the key question is, are we going to let big business control us or are we going to control them? 10 words that are an extremely pithy and absolutely on point summary of the issue that faces us with respect to antitrust and all these other policy areas, and that also point to where economics as a field went wrong, and where just overall policy making has shrunk to a shriveled bare imitation of its former self, in terms of what its ambitions were and what was on the table.
I think that given that it’s now a matter of consensus or nearing consensus that the economy that we live in is not functioning well to the benefit of all, and that really we went wrong somewhere, even if you don’t agree with me that antitrust is a big component of where we went wrong, I think it’s a little hard to deny that economic outcomes are not what they should be.
This whole idea that we really lost something profound and need to win it back I think is going to become a lot more attractive beyond the set of relatively small people like me and Lina who are really focused on this issue of antitrust policy and what the point of that is.
He had seen enough of the move to an active antitrust policy in the second half of the new deal to have something to say about that by the 1939 republication. He also has a lot of very interesting comments about the relationship between what we now call macroeconomic policy or macroeconomics in general, and antitrust and market structure. This is a confluence that has not had a lot of interest from economists in the intervening period up until right now.
I would say now there are papers being published that have that flavor to them, but I think that Clark was absolutely on point in terms of trying to locate the ultimate causes for both macroeconomic failures that happened in The Great Depression, and also why what we might think of a Keynesian macroeconomic policy is a good idea, given how much market power is just a pervasive fact about the economy and how big business and its structure, and market concentration give rise to macro phenomena that Keynes and his contemporaries were concerned about.
That is just, it’s a fantastic book. He covers a ton of ground, and it is, I mean maybe it’s especially meaningful to me ’cause I know how thin and pale and pathetic most economics publications are in the intervening 70 years since Clark was writing, but it certainly makes me think that we went seriously awry somewhere along the way, and we need to rediscover the spirit of John Maurice Clark.
Once again, please help us out by rating this podcast and sharing it with your friends. This show is produced by Lisa Gonzalez and Nick Stumo-Langer. Our theme music is Funk Interlude by Dysfunction_AL. For the Institute for Local Self-Reliance, I’m Stacy Mitchell. I hope you’ll join us again in two weeks for the next episode of Building Local Power.
Like this episode? Please help us reach a wider audience by rating Building Local Power on iTunes or wherever you find your podcasts. And please become a subscriber! If you missed our previous episodes make sure to bookmark our Building Local Power Podcast Homepage.
If you have show ideas or comments, please email us at [email protected]. Also, join the conversation by talking about #BuildingLocalPower on Twitter and Facebook!
Audio Credit: Funk Interlude by Dysfunction_AL Ft: Fourstones – Scomber (Bonus Track). Copyright 2016 Licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial (3.0) license.
Photo Credit: Fibonacci Blue via Flickr.
Follow the Institute for Local Self-Reliance on Twitter and Facebook and, for monthly updates on our work, sign-up for our ILSR general newsletter.
6,068 Listeners
9,066 Listeners
3,861 Listeners
364 Listeners
38,208 Listeners
558 Listeners
32,028 Listeners
412 Listeners
28 Listeners
45 Listeners
86,340 Listeners
9,608 Listeners
15,873 Listeners
14,524 Listeners
481 Listeners
15,316 Listeners
10,238 Listeners